Main menu:

History of RPE Thought

Posts by Tag

RSS New from the CCPA

  • Pharmacare consensus principles released today September 24, 2018
    A diverse coalition representing health care providers, non-profit organizations, workers, seniors, patients and academics has come together to issue a statement of consensus principles for the establishment of National Pharmacare in Canada. Our coalition believes that National Pharmacare should be a seamless extension of the existing universal health care system in Canada, which covers medically […]
    Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives
  • Kate McInturff Fellowship in Gender Justice September 19, 2018
    The CCPA is pleased to announce the creation of the Kate McInturff Fellowship in Gender Justice.This Fellowship is created to honour the legacy of senior researcher Kate McInturff who passed away in July 2018. Kate was a feminist trailblazer in public policy and gender-based research and achieved national acclaim for researching, writing, and producing CCPA’s […]
    Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives
  • The buck-a-beer challenge Ontario deserves September 6, 2018
    Ricardo Tranjan proposes an alternate plan to Doug Ford's buck-a-beer challenge in the Toronto Star.
    Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives
  • Growing number of professionals face job insecurity, study finds September 6, 2018
    The Toronto Star's Sara Mojtehedzadeh discusses the findings of the CCPA Ontario's report, No Safe Harbour and gathers firsthand accounts from precariously employed professionals who live and work in Ontario.
    Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives
  • Our Schools/Our Selves: The view from West Virginia September 4, 2018
    Our latests publication, Lesson Here, digs in to the West Viriginia teachers' strike.  Read the firsthand accounts of the work stoppage here.
    Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives
Progressive Bloggers

Meta

Recent Blog Posts

Posts by Author

Recent Blog Comments

The Progressive Economics Forum

Corporate Taxes and Jobs: Myers Discovers the Business Cycle

I have reviewed Jayson Myers’ recent Canadian Manufacturers and Exporters report on corporate tax cuts, which I made public yesterday.

Proponents of lower corporate taxes usually argue that these will help Canada compete with other countries in attracting internationally-mobile investment. However, as Myers admits, “over the past decade, reductions in Canada’s effective and average combined statutory corporate tax rates have had little observable impact on net flows of foreign direct investment into the country” (page 13).

Significantly, Myers does not claim to find any positive relationship between lower corporate tax rates and investment, employment, innovation, growth or incomes. All of his numbers are based on positive correlations between after-tax corporate profits (or cash flows) and these variables.

It is certainly possible to measure corporate tax cuts as increases in after-tax profits. However, as Myers’ own graph shows (page 15), changes in tax rates are not the main driver of changes in Canadian after-tax profits. A correlation with profits is not the same as a correlation with corporate taxes.

Profits and Jobs

Myers actually does not find a very close correlation between after-tax profits and employment (page 16), so he instead focuses on the unemployment rate (page 17). His summary mistakenly states, “Close positive relationships exist between: Canada’s unemployment rate and after-tax business profits” (page 3), implying that higher unemployment corresponds to higher profits. As noted later, “it is a negative relationship” (page 17).

This negative correlation is hardly surprising. During booms, profits go up and unemployment goes down. In recessions, profits fall and unemployment rises. Indeed, Myers’ graph of profits and unemployment looks like a graph of Canadian business cycles (top of page 17).

However, correlation is not the same as a causal relationship. It is always possible that a third factor – such as the business cycle – is driving both variables.

Even if there is a causal relationship, it is unclear which way the causation runs. Myers’ story is that higher business profits cause more hiring, which causes lower unemployment. But an equally plausible story is that lower unemployment causes more consumer spending, which causes higher business profits.

To manufacture his conclusion, Myers works back from profits to tax cuts and from the unemployment rate to numbers of jobs: “planned federal and provincial corporate tax rate reductions in 2011 and 2012 can be expected to: Lower Canada’s unemployment rate by 0.52 percentage points and boost employment by 98,800 net jobs” (page 4).

Cash Flow and Investment

Myers proceeds to apply the same “methodology” to investment as well as research and development, but changes the explanatory variable from after-tax profits to after-tax cash flows. Profits exclude capital consumption allowances, the amounts that business must invest just to cover the depreciation of existing assets. Cash flow is profit plus these allowances.

There is obviously a pretty strong connection between capital cost allowances and actual investment to cover depreciation. This connection is on top of the business-cycle relationship between profits and new investment. Hence there is an undeniable correlation between cash flow and total investment, but it has nothing to do with corporate tax rates.

Myers makes another notable admission in this area: “Canadian businesses have invested a declining share of after-tax cash flow in both new facilities and machinery and equipment over the past thirty years” (page 21). So, cash given to corporate Canada with no strings attached will not necessarily be invested here. Indeed, corporate taxes could be increased without cutting into the cash used to finance investment.

Magic Tax Cuts

Myers goes back to straight after-tax profits in examining overall economic growth, personal income and government revenue. Of course, all of these variables are subject to the same business cycle as unemployment and investment.

Based on the correlation among after-tax profits, growth and incomes, Myers argues, “The one percentage point reduction in the federal corporate income tax rate implemented in 2010 added 0.5% to Canada’s GDP last year and as a result can be expected to boost the personal income of Canadians by 0.4% or $4.7 billion” (page 28).

Since government revenues are based on GDP and personal income, he concludes that “Lower corporate income tax rates increase overall government revenues” (page 29). By comparison, the typical supply-side contention is that tax cuts increase government revenue until it reaches the Laffer Curve’s peak.

Myers’ claim is subject to no such limit. Anytime the public sector needs money, it can just give $1 to the corporate sector and watch it turn into more than $4 of additional GDP, which yields about $1.60 of tax revenue.

Unfortunately, most of that money would go to other levels of government. But I am sure a federal-provincial accord can be negotiated to put this perpetual revenue-generating machine into action!

Again, Myers’ report is not about corporate tax rates or their possible incentive effects. In his model, corporate tax cuts matter only insofar as they increase after-tax profits. Rather than implementing planned corporate tax cuts at an annual cost of $6.2 billion, Ottawa might as well just write corporate Canada a series of postdated cheques for $6.2 billion each.

Misleading Premises

Before the report starts making Voodoo economics look cautious, its opening section compares statutory corporate tax rates in Canada and other countries. Myers argues, in bold text, that “Canada’s combined corporate tax rate needs to fall to 25% simply to allow Canada to catch up with the rest of the world” (page 11).

However, his benchmarks are unweighted averages of the OECD and the whole world, which are artificially dragged down by small tax havens. As I noted years ago, these averages are appreciably higher when countries are weighted according to GDP. Canada was already in line with appropriately weighted OECD and global averages before the current round of corporate tax cuts.

Of course, the United States has a relatively high statutory corporate tax rate and the world’s largest GDP. But Myers contends that it has a lower effective corporate tax rate and, in bold text, that “Canada’s combined corporate tax rate needs to fall to 25% simply to allow Canada to remain competitive with the United States in terms of the percentage of profits that are actually left in the hands of business” (page 12).

However, his graph actually shows that effective corporate tax rates (i.e. revenues/profits) have been almost identical in the two countries, at least since 2000 (page 12). Canada’s effective rate jumped up in 2010, when the Department of Finance attributed “higher-than-expected corporate income tax revenues” to “exceptional one-time factors.” A one-year blip in revenue hardly makes the case for ongoing corporate tax cuts.

Enjoy and share:

Comments

Comment from Keith Newman
Time: January 13, 2011, 4:13 pm

It seems to me Mr. Myers has reworked the old editor’s trick of writing a headline and leading with a first paragraph neither of which have anything to do with the content of the article. Since almost no-one reads beyond the first paragraph the great majority of readers will retain the false information even if the truth is actually in the article.

In this case it is the press release that is the fabrication.

Comment from Erin Weir
Time: January 13, 2011, 4:49 pm

Indeed. And to further reduce the number of people who read beyond the press release, the Canadian Manufacturers and Exporters’ website provides the report only to people logged in as members.

Comment from George Hambleton
Time: January 14, 2011, 9:38 am

I agree wholeheartedly. One fact, however, is inescapable: Corporations don’t pay taxes; their customers do.

Consequently, I’d like to see those corporations taxed where I don’t shop.

Comment from Purple Library Guy
Time: January 16, 2011, 7:39 pm

People are always saying that, but I really doubt it. It’s just one of the arguments corporations use in their incredibly strenuous efforts not to be taxed: Oh, there’s no point taxing us, we’ll just pass the costs along. Yeah? If that’s so why do they push so hard not to be taxed? Theoretically, if it’s true then money spent lobbying for lower corporate taxes is irrationally spent. But they keep on spending it . . .

Comment from Erin Weir
Time: January 21, 2011, 1:31 pm

Another point is that many of the same economists who decry corporate taxes for allegedly being passed onto consumers also advocate higher consumption taxes.

Comment from George Hambleton
Time: January 25, 2011, 3:52 pm

I pay little attention to the chatter from the anonymous. I do, however, sincerely appreciate your response, Erin. You raised a valid point of which I was unaware. Thanks for that.

Comment from Mel Barns
Time: March 16, 2011, 7:43 am

So if higher after-tax profits lead to higher employment, just where is this employment created? The answer: not necessarily domestically but where-ever in the world labour rates are lowest.

Write a comment





Related articles